Skip to main content

Full text of "Management 205a - International Economics"

See other formats


101.1 


© Daniel J.B. Mitchell (See cover page for details.) 


Strategic Trade Policy 

The Ricardian analysis of international trade suggested that the 
gains from trade came from technological differences i.e., 
international differences in productivities. It assumed constant 
returns to scale and a perfectly competitive economy. The 2-factor 
model and the related Heckscher-Ohlin analysis suggested that the 
gains from trade stemmed from international differences in factor 
endowments again under the assumption of perfect competition and 
constant returns to scale. 

In Section 17, we have already noted that assuming increasing 
returns to scale (diminishing average and marginal costs, economies 
of scale) can change the analysis. We noted there, for examples that 
two countries might have gains from trade based on exploiting 
increasing returns . Left unsaid at that point was that industries with 
economies of scale in the relevant range are unlikely to be purely 
competitive. This is because there is an advantage to the firm that 
increases its share of the market the most. It experiences the 
greatest reduction in costs (and therefore a cost advantage relative 
to smaller competitors) . If an industry ends up with one (or a few) 
big firms, it won't be perfectly competitive. Rather, it will be 
monopolistic or oligopolistic. 

There are gains for a country to exploit if it can dominate an 
industry and thereby extract a monopolistic rent from consumers in 
other countries. The world as a whole may not be better off in such 
a case (although it might benefit from exploitation of economies from 
scale) , but the country whose producer (s) receive (s) these rents may 
be better off. Hence, there is a potential role for what has been 
termed "strategic trade policies," i.e., national policies of trade 
restriction and/or subsidy to enable non-competitive industries to 
obtain monopoly rents . 

To some extent, the arguments that countries should follow 
"industrial policies" which favor certain industries fall into this 
category. Some of the arguments for preventing other countries from 
predatory dumping or subsidizing their exports also can be 
rationalized on these grounds. The importing country may fear 
eventually being forced to pay monopoly rents to foreigners . 


101.2 


Our discussion of trade integration in section 100 noted that 
in a world of "second best" conditions, free trade is not necessarily 
optimal. Where there are non-competitive elements we are in a 
second-best world. Similarly, our discussion of the terms-of-trade 
effect of tariffs (section 70) and the case in section 14 illustrated 
the possibility of a country gaining by exploiting another country 
as a monopsonist or monopolist. Thus, it is possible that free trade 
is not optimal when there are increasing returns to scale and that 
a strategic trade policy (tariff, subsidy, quota, etc.) may be better 
for the imposing country than free trade. 

A substantial amount of effort in international trade theory has 
gone into modeling these notions. As yet, it is difficult to point 
to handy rules-of-thumb that would tell a country what policy is best. 
And policies imposed may be offset by retaliation from other countries 
Thus, international trade economists still tend to favor free trade 
on pragmatic grounds. They argue that because it is hard in practice 
to know whether a strategic trade policy will help or hurt, and because 
retaliation may occur, it is better not to embark on strategic trade 
policies at all. But there are many who argue for selective government 
interventions along lines outlined above. These issues will not be 
resolved definitively, but there are benefits to be had from 
accumulating case study evidence relating to the results of 
particular attempts at strategic trade policy.